SANCTIONS ON SOUTH AFRICA: WHAT DID THEY DO?

Facebooktwitterredditpinterestlinkedinmail

ECONOMIC GROWTH CENTER

YALE UNIVERSITY

P.O. Box 208269

27 Hillhouse Avenue

New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8269

CENTER DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 796

Philip I. Levy

Yale University

February 1999

Note: Center Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussions and critical

comments.

SANCTIONS ON SOUTH AFRICA: WHAT DID THEY DO?

Philip I. Levy

Yale University

February 1999

Abstract

This paper considers the economic sanctions that were applied in the mid-1980s to

pressure the South African government to end apartheid. It asks what role those sanctions

played in the eventual demise of the apartheid regime and concludes that the role was

probably very small. An alternative explanation for the regime change is offered: the

communist bloc combined to bring about the change. If one is to argue for the efficacy of

sanctions, two key obstacles are their limited economic impact and the substantial lag

between the imposition of sanctions and the political change. Since sanctions preceded

the change of government, it is impossible to rule them out as a determinant. However,

their principal effect was probably psychological. The implication is that the South

African case should not serve as the lone major instance of effective sanctions.

Keywords: Sanctions, South Africa, Political Economy, Trade

J.E.L. classification: F14

2

Sanctions on South Africa: What did they do?

by Philip I. Levy*

Although careful studies of economic sanctions have cast doubt on their

effectiveness,1 anecdotes can be powerful rhetorical tools. A single important case that

demonstrates sanctions’ potential allows advocates to argue that their cause is more akin

to the success than to the failures. Frequently, advocates point to the case of sanctions

applied in the mid-1980s against the apartheid regime in South Africa as just such a case.

On the face of it, South African sanctions appear to have been successful. In

response to the outrages of apartheid, many countries adopted trade and financial

sanctions and a significant amount of foreign investment was withdrawn from South

Africa. After the adoption of sanctions, South Africa experienced economic difficulty and

numerous domestic actors commented on how the economic situation was untenable and

required political change. By 1994, Nelson Mandela had been elected President of South

Africa. He and other black leaders attributed to economic sanctions a significant role in

bringing about the democratic transition.

This paper will also present an alternative view. One can tell a story of the change

in South Africa in which any positive contribution of trade sanctions was trivial and they

might even have deferred the achievement of the campaign’s objectives. The international

economic actions against South Africa that were most damaging were taken by private

actors, not governments. The actions taken by governments were not especially

economically damaging. To some extent, they caused the Nationalist Party government to

stiffen its repression. In this alternative story, the demise of apartheid, which followed

* Department of Economics, Yale University, P.O. Box 208269, New Haven, CT, 06520-

8269. E-mail: philip.levy@yale.edu. I am grateful to Stefan Krieger, T.N. Srinivasan and

William Foltz for helpful conversations.

1 Hufbauer, Schott and Elliott (1990) is the most thorough study of economic sanctions

and they find them to be effective roughly one third of the time. Morgan and Schwebach

(1997) use an expanded data set to argue that this rate significantly overstates the

effectiveness of sanctions.

3

sanctions with a substantial lag, can be attributed to three different factors: the

effectiveness of the political opposition of the black majority; the inefficiency and growing

economic cost of the apartheid system; and the fall of the Soviet Union.2

Alongside this alternative case the paper will try to illuminate the kind of

arguments that one must make if one is to argue that sanctions were effective. The

fundamental problem in assessing the role of sanctions is that the end of apartheid was

overdetermined. Given the sequence of events, it is impossible to prove that sanctions

were ineffective; they were among the many potential “causes” linked to the single

“effect.”3 In lieu of such a proof, the rest of the paper will describe the sequence of events

in South Africa, consider what it would mean for sanctions to be effective, and argue that

at best sanctions failed to interfere with the other forces that were bringing down the

apartheid regime.

I. The Sanctions Timeline

The apartheid regime against which sanctions were targeted had been in place

since the National Party took power in 1948. Prior to the episodes of the mid-1980s, the

United Nations adopted an arms embargo in the early 1960s and OPEC nations applied an

oil embargo starting in 1973.4 The focus of this paper will be the multilateral sanctions of

1985-87, particularly those dealing with trade.5

If those sanctions were to have played an important role in undermining the

apartheid economy, one would expect the imposition of sanctions to mark a break in

economic performance. In fact, the break for South Africa occurred much earlier. In the

2 Lowenberg (1997) offers a useful analysis of the reasons for the failure of the apartheid

economy.

3 Of course, with a larger set of countries, one could use econometrics to sort out the

determinants, but that would lead us back to the careful studies showing the

ineffectiveness of sanctions.

4 Up until the fall of the Shah in 1979, though, Iran continued to supply South Africa with oil. Lewis

(1990, p. 103).

5 There are a number of thorough tellings of the story of recent South African history. For

a general account, see Waldmeier (1997). For ones more focused on the effect of

sanctions, see Manby (1992) and Hufbauer, Schott and Elliott (1990).

4

decades leading up to 1974, real GDP in South Africa grew an average of 4.9 percent per

year. From 1974 to 1987 it averaged 1.8 percent per year.6 In the immediate aftermath of

the mid-1980s sanctions, GDP growth accelerated: it was 0.5 percent in 1986, 2.6 percent

in 1987, and 3.2 percent in 1988.7

The early-1970s break was contemporaneous with the oil embargo and the

worldwide oil crisis, which can certainly serve as one explanation for slower growth. In

addition, a number of factors beyond the oil shock combined to slow the expansion; two

are worth noting here.

First, labor market distortions were inherent to the apartheid system. Blacks

constituted the majority of the population but were restricted in their travel and in the jobs

that they could hold. One goal of the apartheid system was to keep blacks living in

separate areas from whites. As the South African economy developed, however, the

employment restrictions bound tightly. An expanding manufacturing sector created a

demand for additional workers in the cities at the same time that a central goal of

apartheid was to keep blacks out of cities and in separate homelands. In 1973, in response

to the resulting labor shortages, blacks were allowed to work at skilled jobs in white areas.

This was a dramatic undermining of the rationale of apartheid and was only the first in a

series of reforms in which the employment restrictions were relaxed.8 Nonetheless, even

when blacks were allowed to take jobs they had previously been denied, restrictions

remained and along with them an extensive bureaucracy to maintain apartheid.

The second notable factor in South Africa’s economic slowdown was the role of

external borrowing. South Africa pursued a policy of import substitution industrialization.

6 Jones and Muller (1992, p. 296).

7 Lipton (1989, p. 348). She also notes that there was increased activity in the informal

sector at that time so the figures may be underestimates. Note, though, that GDP growth

rates were lagging behind population growth.

8 Waldmeier (1997, p. 26). Stressing the importance of this change, she writes, “as the far

right warned at the time, jobs could not ultimately be shared with blacks without sharing

power as well.” Also see Lowenberg (1997) on the importance of labor market distortions

as a barrier to growth.

5

From the 1940s to 1984, South Africa ran current account deficits on the order of 2 to 3

percent of GDP.9 These were offset by substantial capital inflows. This dependence on

foreign capital left South Africa vulnerable to shifts in lending. One such shift occurred in

the period 1976-1980, when there was a net foreign capital outflow averaging 2.3 percent

of GDP.10 By the mid-1980s, South Africa’s external debt was roughly $24 billion, of

which two-thirds was short-term.11 This structure left South Africa dependent on the

willingness of foreign lenders to refinance.

Throughout this time, there was an anti-apartheid political movement that was

pressuring the government. A major turning point was the 1976 Soweto uprising. It began

as a revolt against a government plan to teach Afrikaans in black schools, drew

international attention and prompted the United Nations arms embargo as well as private

codes of conduct for foreign firm operating in South Africa. There was persistent

international condemnation of the apartheid regime, but no major economic sanctions

were adopted until later. Responding to reform pressures, in 1984 the South African

government adopted a new constitution that gave Indians and “coloreds” some right to

participate but continued to exclude blacks. Unrest in South Africa persisted and

intensified and the government responded with repression. In July of 1985, President P.W.

Botha declared a state of emergency. Shortly thereafter, Chase Manhattan Bank declared

it would not renew its short-term loans, touching off a liquidity crisis as other lenders

followed suit.

All of this preceded the multilateral economic sanctions. While foreign companies

doing business in South Africa experienced pressure in their home countries to disinvest, it

is difficult to distinguish the effects of this pressure from South Africa’s diminishing appeal

as a borrower. One Chase executive explained his company’s withdrawal by saying, “We

9 Jones and Müller (1990, p. 299).

10 Lewis (1990, p. 178).

11 Waldmeier (1997, p. 56). To put the number in perspective, South African GNP in 1984

was $70 billion (Hufbauer, Schott and Elliott, p. 246), so external debt was almost 35

percent of GNP.

6

felt that the risk attached to political unrest and economic instability became too high for

our investors. We decided to withdraw. It was never the intention to facilitate change in

South Africa, the decision was taken purely on account of what was in the interest of

Chase and its assets.”12

It is also important to distinguish between private and public acts. The financial

crisis was brought on by the decisions of private lenders who saw a deteriorating political

and economic situation and doubted the country’s creditworthiness. For the purpose of

public policy discussions, this privately induced financial crisis — the repercussions of

which were substantially greater than any of the public sanctions that ensued — cannot be

used as evidence of sanctions’ effectiveness.

In August of 1985, President Botha gave a speech intended to introduce further

reforms to apartheid. The reforms, however, were substantially less than what the

international community had been expecting. The crisis intensified, the South African

Rand fell further and in late August the government temporarily closed the stock exchange

and foreign-exchange markets and suspended interest payments on its debt.

II. Sanctions deployed

The mounting frustration with the persistence of apartheid, coupled with South

Africa’s apparent economic vulnerability, prompted a round of multilateral economic

sanctions. In September 1985 the European Community imposed a set of very limited

trade and financial sanctions on South Africa, and the Commonwealth countries adopted

similar measures in October. In the United States, the Reagan administration was opposed

to South African sanctions but imposed a limited export ban to head off stronger action in

Congress.

The political and financial crises in South Africa continued as the government

failed to reach agreement with its creditors. In December, it extended its freeze on debt

12 Quoted in Waldmeier (1997, p. 56). I draw on Hufbauer, Schott and Elliott (1990, pp.

221-235) for their detailed timeline of events surrounding the imposition of sanctions.

7

repayments until March 1986. In February 1986, an interim agreement with creditors was

reached and in March Botha lifted the state of emergency. The state of emergency was

reimposed in June, however, as the tenth anniversary of the Soweto uprising approached.

In the fall of 1986, the second and more significant round of sanctions ensued. In

September, the EC banned imports of iron, steel, gold coins from and new investments in

South Africa. They did not, however, extend this ban to cover the most important South

African exports, such as coal, diamonds or other forms of gold. Japan passed similar

sanctions shortly thereafter, although omitting iron ore. In the United States, Congress

passed the Comprehensive Anti-Apartheid Act (CAAA).13 President Reagan vetoed the

legislation, but his veto was overridden in October. The CAAA severely restricted lending

to South Africa (although not loan rescheduling) and imposed import bans on iron, steel,

coal, uranium, textiles, and agricultural goods. Strategic materials, diamonds, and most

forms of gold were omitted.14

The direct impact of the trade sanctions was limited. South Africa developed

extensive measures to circumvent the sanctions, although these sometimes involved costly

import-substitution. South Africans also were able to transship through countries that

were not participating in the embargoes. In sum, from 1985 to 1989, export volumes rose

by 26 percent, although terms of trade suffered.15 One estimate of the marginal cost to

South Africa of the mid-1980s trade sanctions was $354 million annually, or 0.5 percent

of GNP.16

13 Other countries imposing financial or trade sanctions included the Nordic countries,

Australia and Hong Kong (Hufbauer, Schott and Elliott, 1990, pp. 238-239).

14 Jones and Müller (1992, p. 344). To put this in perspective, gold was easily South

Africa’s largest export. In 1985 it accounted for 42.6 percent of the value of merchandise

exports. Manufactured exports accounted for 33.1 percent, mineral exports for 18.2

percent, and agricultural exports for 2.9 percent.

15 Waldmeier (1997, p. 133).

16 Hufbauer, Schott and Elliott (1990, p. 246). They calculate the losses based on

reduction in trade in the targeted goods relative to the early 1980s and estimating what

fraction of the lost exports constitute a welfare loss (3 percent for gold coins, 30 to 40

percent for other goods). Higher estimates of sanctions’ cost sometimes include the oil

embargo of the 1970s and financial sanctions.

8

There is little doubt that the reversal of the flow of capital into South Africa was

far more painful economically than trade sanctions. The doubt concerns how much these

effects can be attributed to public rather than private measures. The effort by the banks to

withdraw preceded the imposition of sanctions and seemed to show that South Africa’s

faltering economy, market uncertainties and political turmoil had made it an unattractive

site for investment. In fact, the outflow of dividends and profits from existing investments

in South Africa exceeded new FDI,17 thus presenting default as an attractive option for the

country and an important concern for sanctioning governments. Thus, it is not clear how

binding restrictions on further lending were.

The disinvestment campaign, which largely consisted of private pressure but also

included some government action, may have been most costly to the foreign firms that

withdrew. In the words of one observer, “Many disinvesting companies simply sold their

assets cheaply to local white businessmen, but maintained non-equity links such as

franchise, licensing, and technology agreements that permitted them to keep operating.”18

Further, in September 1985 South Africa introduced a dual exchange rate regime to

discourage disinvestment, whereby those firms that wished to repatriate their holdings did

so at the “financial rand” rate, which was frequently at a 40 percent discount to the

commercial rate.

Finally, there were non-economic sanctions, such as the prohibition against South

African participation in international rugby and cricket competitions.

Although these sanctions were in place, the repression of the black majority

continued and at times intensified. In early 1988, for example, the government banned all

major nonwhite opposition groups and prohibited political activity by trade unions.19

During the late 1980s, however, secret negotiations were underway between

representatives of the government and leaders of the African National Congress (ANC).

17 Lewis (1990, p. 110).

18 Waldmeier (1997, p. 133).

19 Hufbauer, Schott and Elliott (1990, p. 229).

9

Eventually, in February 1990 Nelson Mandela was released from prison. In April 1994,

with a new South African constitution negotiated, Nelson Mandela won the first all-race

elections to become President.

III. Judging the Effectiveness of Sanctions

One can ask what criteria one should apply to determine effectiveness. Hufbauer,

Schott and Elliott (1990) rank on a scale of 1 to 4 the extent to which the goals of

sanctions were achieved and the extent to which sanctions contributed to the achievement.

They multiply the scores and if the result is 9 or greater, they deem sanctions successful.

At the time of publication, they assigned the mid-1980s sanctions against South Africa a 2

for effectiveness and a 3 for sanctions’ contribution — unsuccessful. Presumably now,

since all the stated goals of the CAAA have been met, they would deem the sanctions

successful. Their score for sanctions’ contribution, however, is open to debate.

One measure of sanctions’ effectiveness could be the extent of economic damage

they inflict on the target country. Although the trade sanction cost of 0.5 percent of GNP

is not trivial, neither is it very large. Kaempfer and Lowenberg (1988) argue that targeted

sanctions can impose minimal economic hardship and still effect policy change. However,

the South African sanctions were not tightly targeted; whites often benefited from the firesale

disinvestment and blacks were often hurt by the loss of jobs.

Perhaps a clearer standard for the effectiveness of sanctions, particularly in a case

in which the goals were so well defined, is whether the goals would have been achieved in

the absence of the sanctions. In the South African case, the goals were clearly achieved,

albeit after a lengthy interval. The question is whether sanctions played an integral role.

Below the case is made for and against.

IV. An “effective sanctions” story

Although the direct economic impact of governmentally imposed sanctions was

quite small, one could argue that they were the “final straw” that made economic

10

conditions intolerable and forced political change. There were numerous contemporaneous

statements from South Africans that drew such a link between the economic climate and

political change, although they were usually accompanied by denials of sanctions’ role.

However, one might discount such denials as an effort to dissuade foreign governments

from further sanctions.

Certainly an important set of evidence in favor of sanctions’ effectiveness is the

statements by black leaders expounding upon their importance. Bishop Desmond Tutu,

Rev. Allan Boesak, and Nelson Mandela all made such statements. Even upon Mandela’s

release from prison in 1990, he said, “To lift sanctions now would be to run the risk of

aborting the process toward ending apartheid.”20

Their arguments may have less to do with tipping an economic balance than with

sanctions’ psychological impact. The sanctions signaled the extent to which South Africa

was isolated in the international community. While cultural sanctions played the same role,

perhaps the greater cost of imposing trade sanctions sent a stronger signal. Although

sanctions of one form or another had been in place for a long time, the ones of the mid-

1980s included key South African allies such as the United States in a non-trivial way.

While there was a substantial lag between the imposition of sanctions and the change of

regime, it may have been unrealistic to expect instantaneous change.21

V. An “ineffective sanctions” story

An alternative interpretation of events can be offered in which sanctions played no

important role. Instead, one can identify three factors that led to the downfall of apartheid.

First, the extensive labor market distortions of apartheid proved increasingly costly and

unacceptable. The South Africans linking economic conditions with the need for political

change could well have been sincere in dismissing sanctions; the economic forces

20 Quoted in Hufbauer, Schott and Elliott (1990, p. 233).

21 However, since asymmetric information seemed to play no role here, instant capitulation

would seem to have been more rational than prolonged endurance of sanctions, followed

by capitulation.

11

mandating change were internal. This is supported by the steady relaxation of apartheid

labor laws, beginning in the 1970s, well before serious sanctions.

Second, there was an effective political movement against the apartheid

government. While this movement did not have sufficient power to overthrow the

government by force, it was able to create substantial internal disruption. This political

instability combined with the economic flaws of apartheid (and of the accompanying

program of import-substitution industrialization) to make South Africa unattractive to

foreign investors, both directly and indirectly. The direct effect was the increase in risk.

Indirectly, the measures taken by the government to combat the turmoil raised spending

and taxes, thus further diminishing South Africa’s attractiveness as a host for FDI.

Despite these two effects, which were in full play by the mid-1980s, the apartheid

regime remained in power. The final key ingredient in the change was the fall of

communism in Eastern Europe and Mikhail Gorbachev’s forswearing of regional proxy

wars. The Afrikaner government of South Africa saw the ANC as a party of godless

communists, ready to take their country into the communist bloc. Once the communist

bloc fell apart and a withdrawal of Cuban troops from Angola was negotiated, a political

deal with the ANC became conceivable.22

The timing of this story works better than that of the “effective sanctions” version.

Shortly after the imposition of the mid-1980s sanctions, repression intensified. Observers

have attributed this, at least in part, to President Botha’s strong reaction against foreign

interference. Other sanctions had been signaling the world’s disapproval since the early

1960s without prompting any change. Yet once the perceived communist threat

diminished, the release of Mandela and negotiations on a transition followed fairly

quickly.23

22 Waldmeier (1997) describes the anti-communism of the Afrikaners.

23 To be fair, this time period also coincided with F.W. de Klerk’s succession to the South

African Presidency. One could argue whether this change was essential.

12

While it is clear that sanctions had a psychological impact, this was nowhere near

enough to swing the balance against apartheid. As long as the staunchly nationalist

Afrikaners perceived themselves as facing complete disaster should they succumb to a

communist foe, a small decrease in the payoff to persisting in apartheid did nothing to alter

the government’s course of action. Once it became clear that a negotiated solution might

be palatable, the public sanctions were an unnecessary addition to the substantial

incentives to talk.

VI. Conclusion

It is impossible to argue conclusively that trade sanctions failed in the South

African case. Given the small economic effects of trade sanctions, an argument for their

effectiveness ends up hinging on their psychological impact on the governing party. Most

South African leaders claimed the impact was minimal, but one can choose not to believe

them. Such issues are very difficult to resolve; the best one can do is argue that it is

implausible that trade sanctions played a significant and positive role. This paper has

attempted to do so by offering an alternative interpretation that seems to fit the events

more closely and that offers no role for governmentally imposed sanctions. At the very

least, this should cast serious doubt on the applicability of the South African case as a

model for further trade sanctions.

13

References

Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, Jeffrey J. Schott, and Kimberly Ann Elliott. Economic

Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, 2nd Edition, Washington

D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1990.

Jones, Stuart and Andre Müller. The South African Economy, 1910-90, New York: St.

Martin’s Press, 1992.

Kaempfer, William H., and Anton D. Lowenberg. “The Theory of International

Economic Sanctions: A Public Choice Approach,” American Economic Review,

September 1988, 78(4), pp. 786-93.

Lewis, Stephen. The Economics of Apartheid, New York: Council on Foreign Relations,

1990.

Lipton, Merle. “The Challenge of Sanctions,” South African Journal of Economics,

December 1989, 57(4), pp. 336-61.

Lowenberg, Anton D. “Why South Africa’s Apartheid Economy Failed,” Contemporary

Economic Policy, July 1997, XV, pp. 62-72.

Manby, Bronwen,. “South Africa: The Impact of Sanctions,” Journal of International

Affairs, Summer 1992, 46(1), pp. 193-217.

Morgan, T. Clifton and Valerie L. Schwebach, “Fools Suffer Gladly: The Use of

Economic Sanctions in International Crises,” International Studies Quarterly,

March 1997, 41(4), pp. 27-50.

Waldmeir, Patti. Anatomy of a Miracle: the End of Apartheid, New York: W.W.

Norton, 1997.

http://www.econ.yale.edu/growth_pdf/cdp796.pdf

Facebooktwitterredditpinterestlinkedinmail